Content pfp
Content
@
0 reply
0 recast
0 reaction

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
Going to give a *sneak peak* about this paper w/ @ksk and others to FC before Twitter! There's been a surge of interest in intent-based systems like @uniswapX or CoW Swap — their claim has been to help improve the acquisition of off-chain price data on-chain But do they work?
9 replies
23 recasts
96 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
In general, there is often the advice that you get in auction mechanism design of, "it is better for revenue and/or welfare to have more bidders in an auction than to have a better reserve prices/parameters" In fact, this is the content of the Bulow-Klemperer theorem! https://www.cs.tau.ac.il/~fiat/mdsem12/amd05.pdf
1 reply
0 recast
9 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
But does "more solvers (bidders) = better welfare for the user" for intents? In our paper, we find that this is *paradoxically* not always true! In fact, a user using an auction like @uniswapX may actually want to *purposely limit the number of solvers* who find prices for them Does this mean intents are broken? Nah
1 reply
0 recast
12 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
But it does say that you need to be careful when you design your intents — if you aren't cognizant of the microstructure you create, you might actually make the intent market worse than the fully on-chain market (e.g. a Uniswap V3 CFMM, in the case of UniswapX) So why would a user want *fewer* solvers competing?
1 reply
0 recast
12 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
A problem arises when solvers incur a) costs in order to be able to participate in the intent market b) amount they have to spend to get best execution prices off-chain A solver in an intent market faces the 1st cost, they face *costly entry* whereas the 2nd cost is *costly effort*
1 reply
0 recast
7 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
Costly entry: Have to buy a lot of servers and colocate w/ both ETH validators + Binance in order to effectively bid in intent auctions Costly effort: To get the best possible price on Binance, I need to spend money to ensure that my slippage/impact costs are low In some cases, you can't *avoid* costly effort
1 reply
0 recast
6 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
Concrete example — Consider two scenarios for a user: 1) Buy $1,000,000 of ETH 2) Buy $1,000,000 of WIF 1st: Many solvers are long ETH and don't have to buy ETH from an exchange to fulfill (low costs) 2nd Case: Few MMs hold WIF so they have to buy it — if they all do it at the same time they face congestion costs
1 reply
0 recast
8 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
This example shows that intent solvers face congestion costs due to inventory constraints — if they hold inventory of an asset, they don't have compete with other solvers for procurement but if they don't, then they all simultaneously hit the same off-chain venue and cause the execution price to get worse
1 reply
0 recast
6 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
This notion of 'congestion cost' due to lack of inventory gets passed on to the user: the solvers bid less aggressively This type of 'collusive' behavior where all bidders bid below their true value for an item is known as 'bid shading' (a common problem in ad auctions) https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bid_shading
1 reply
0 recast
11 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
The difference between intent systems (eg @anoma, @uniswap, @flashbots, etc.) and ad auctions, however, is that ad auctions have *explicit* collusion In intent systems, the collusion is 'implicit' — its because solvers congest each other, worsening welfare https://pubsonline.informs.org/doi/10.1287/mnsc.2019.3457
1 reply
0 recast
9 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
How bad can congestion be? We show that if the congestion costs (e.g. slippage + price impact on off-chain venues) are sufficiently high then you can have oligopoly (e.g. it is better for a user want fewer solvers participating to get better prices) As @sui414 and @angelfish have shown, this occurs in practice!
1 reply
0 recast
9 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
But defining oligopoly is a bit delicate: even if solvers congest themselves such that fewer than the maximum amount participate in equilibrium, is this _really_ worse for the user? To understand this more carefully, we need to define oligopoly formally
1 reply
0 recast
10 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
Oligopoly is defined as two contemporaneous things: 1) If there are n possible bidders, then only k = o(n) bidders participate in equilibrium - i.e. k/n → 0 as n → ∞ (% of solvers that participate goes to 0) 2) Users get worse prices as n increases (so they get better prices with fewer bidders)
1 reply
0 recast
7 reactions

Tarun Chitra pfp
Tarun Chitra
@pinged
We show that oligopoly exists, for many types of costs and prices, if solvers simultaneously face costly entry and costly effort — which means that intent markets may benefit from *restricting entry* (e.g. being *less* decentralized) This is kind of surprising! But read the paper for more (+ ask questions!)
2 replies
0 recast
12 reactions

Praneeth pfp
Praneeth
@praneeth
Ty for this! Will read the paper over this weekend, but from a high level standpoint, will there also be the possibility for solvers to tap into user assets for their fills? Ala coincidence of wants, but maybe even over a number of txn's and pay them a fee for their capital?
0 reply
0 recast
0 reaction